Keith Rankin's Thursday Column
Don Brash has no Plan B
20 January 2000
Yesterday we were
subject to the embarrassing experience of the Reserve
Bank
tightening monetary policy just two hours before the
public announcement of
a December quarter inflation rate
of just 0.2 percent. The Bank had forecast
that the
inflation rate would be much higher.
Despite the 1990s'
experiences of the United States and Australia,
Governor
Brash believes that inflation follows economic
growth and that growth must
therefore be checked. Whereas
the Keynesians in the 1970s couldn't explain
simultaneous
high inflation, low growth and high unemployment,
the
monetarists of today cannot explain simultaneous
falling unemployment, high
growth and minuscule
inflation. So they are in denial, basing policy on
their
own flawed beliefs about inflation.
While the Reserve Bank
certainly is "trigger-happy" (as the Minister of
Finance
said yesterday), its problem is much deeper than
premature
tightening. The Bank is unable to develop
alternative views on inflation
because to do so would be
an admission that the last 15 years of monetary
policy
had been an expensive failure. Unlike Alan Greenspan who
uses
intuition to override the monetarist manual, Don
Brash continues to be
guided by a rulebook that owes much
to clapped-out ideology and virtually
nothing to the
scientific method.
For the best part of 8 years, Greenspan
has refrained from tightening
monetary policy despite
forecasts of rising inflation. Following
his
reappointment to a fourth term as Chairman of the US
Federal Reserve Bank,
Greenspan hinted at a return to the
rule book. Economic progressives
(including Robert Reich
who came here as a guest of the New Zealand Labour
Party)
plus political conservatives in the Republican Party, rushed
to
suggest that he may be too concerned about something
that will not happen.
Y2K was a real threat; inflation is
not.
Friedman's first edition of the monetarist rule book
said that central banks
must control the money supply so
that the quantity of money in any nation
grows at a
steady rate of three percent each year. It didn't work
because
most instances of rising prices are not caused by
the growth of a nation's
internal money supply, and
because central banks cannot control the supply
of bank
credit from which most money is created.
The second
edition of the rulebook emphasises the manipulation of
interest
rates, through in particular the announcement of
an "Official Cash Rate"
(OCR). Higher interest rates are
supposed to lead to lower inflation rates.
The problem
with this interest rate rule is that the direct effect of
rising
interest rates is to increase rather than decrease
inflation. Interest is
simply the "wages of capital".
Like the wages of labour, interest is a
production cost.
As an economic cost (ie an "opportunity cost") interest
is
much more than debt-servicing. Profit is a form of
interest. Companies must
pay higher dividends when
interest rates for bank deposits are raised.
Monetarist
policies reduce inflation only when indirect effects
outweigh the
direct effects of higher capital costs.
Raising interest rates and hence
business costs causes
marginal businesses to fail. Unemployment
rises.
Surviving firms take on fewer new workers or cut
wages in order to service
their debts, placate
shareholders and pay for the financial and
business
services that they need when in trouble. Because
workers have less to spend
in such a deflationary
environment, firms producing wage goods - ie goods
and
services that workers buy - make heroic attempts to keep
their output
prices down despite rises in
costs.
Another indirect effect only applies to nations
with floating exchange
rates. A rise in interest rates in
New Zealand relative to other countries
leads to a net
inflow of foreign capital and a higher exchange rate.
The
result is that New Zealand exports some of its
increased input inflation,
while "benefiting" from the
rising unemployment that inhibits the growth of
output
inflation.
If we consider the global economy as one,
rising world interest rates lead
to rising rather than
falling world inflation. The irony is that the
countries
leading a rise in interest rates may themselves experience
reduced
inflation. They export their inflation as their
exchange rates rise.
There are times when central banks
should raise interest rates. In a
genuinely overheated
economy, interest rates rise of their own accord
as
overconfident firms compete for credit. A policy that
anticipates such a
rise in market interest rates can
benefit an economy by discouraging too
many firms from
expanding at the same time. Indeed, Alan Greenspan is
more
worried about unsustainable growth in the USA than
about inflation. He does
not have a rigid contract that
overemphasises inflation, as Brash's does.
New Zealand
has not been through a decade of sustained growth, so the
need
to dampen growth is not a valid reason for raising
interest rates in New
Zealand.
In the 1950s and 1960s,
tight monetary policy was used as a response to a
balance
of payments difficulty. Indeed Tuesday's scary balance of
trade data
does, on the surface, offer a much better
reason for tightening monetary
policy than does any
concern about demand inflation.
In the 1950s and 1960s,
firm monetary policy could reduce a balance of
payments
deficit because we had a fixed exchange rate and exchange
controls.
A credit squeeze (as we called it then) led to
reductions in the demand for
goods and services. That
would lead to fewer imports. There would be no
reductions
of exports so long as other countries were not
simultaneously
tightening their monetary policies.
The
problem here is that high interest rates have exactly the
opposite
effect when exchange controls are absent. Now,
a
rise in interest rates generates an increased net
capital inflow. The
balance of payments deficit must be
equal to the net capital inflow.
New Zealand had a huge
net capital inflow in 1999. Hence its huge balance
of
payments deficit.
Higher interest rates in 2000 will
cause (i) the balance of payments deficit
to increase,
(ii) costs to rise, (iii) unemployment to be higher than
it
would otherwise have been, (iv) growth to slow down in
the export and
import-competing sectors, and (v) profits
to rise in industries that are
able to pass on cost
increases. In New Zealand, when monetary policy
tightens,
inflation rises markedly in the non-tradeable
sectors.
Higher interest rates bring gains to the richest
5-10% of the New Zealand
population. Losses that outweigh
the gains are borne by the remaining
90-95%. Indeed, that
is the real story of a monetarist experiment that is
not
over yet. The Reserve Bank perseveres with Plan A because it
cannot
admit to the grief that that game plan has caused
to the people of New
Zealand.
© 2000 Keith
Rankin
Thursday Column Archive (2000): http://pl.net/~keithr/Thursday2000.html